AustLII Home | Databases | WorldLII | Search | Feedback

Journal of Australian Taxation

Business and Economics, Monash University
You are here:  AustLII >> Databases >> Journal of Australian Taxation >> 2015 >> [2015] JlATax 4

Database Search | Name Search | Recent Articles | Noteup | LawCite | Author Info | Download | Help

Drew, Joseph; Dollery, Brian --- "Careful What You Wish For: Rate-Capping in Victorian Local Government" [2015] JlATax 4; (2015) 17(1) Journal of Australian Taxation 139


Careful What You Wish For: Rate-

Capping in Victorian Local

Government

Joseph Drew* and Brian Dollery#

The new Victorian Government won the 2014 election on a

platform to inter alia introduce a cap on council rates in all

Victorian councils. This means that a rate-cap will be introduced

beginning with the 2016/17 financial year, with future rises in

rates pegged at the Consumer Price Index (CPI) after this date.

This paper provides a comparative empirical analysis of New

South Wales local government - the only Australian local

government system to operate a rate-pegging regime - and

Victorian local government with respect to rate-capping. We find

evidence to support the proposition that rate-capping has

deleterious effects on municipal revenue effort, equity, debt and

infrastructure maintenance. Moreover, our findings do not

provide empirical evidence in support of the claim that rate-

capping increases municipal efficiency. The paper concludes by

considering various alternative public policy instruments to rate-

capping.

1. INTRODUCTION

Local government systems worldwide are subject to a myriad

of regulatory regimes, ranging from highly prescriptive to more

laisse faire, with Australian state and territory local government

* Post-Doctoral Fellow, Institute of Public Policy and Governance,

University of Technology Sydney.

# Professor of Economics and Director of the University of New

England Centre for Local Government.

(2015) 17(1)

139

RATE CAPPING IN LOCAL GOVERNMENT

jurisdictions typically at the former end of the spectrum.1 While

the nature of municipal regulation varies widely, state-imposed

limitations on council expenditure and revenue-raising represent

one of its more draconian manifestations. In particular, state-wide

limits on property tax increases, commonly known as ‘rate-

capping’ or ‘rate-pegging’ in Australian local government, are an

especially powerful policy instrument. In general, the rationale

for rate-capping is to restrict the spatial monopoly power of local

government to raise property taxes as it sees fit.2

In the Australian local government milieu, at present only

New South Wales (NSW) has a comprehensive rate-pegging

regime, although the Northern Territory (NT) caps mining and

pastoral rates. In NSW, rate-pegging remains contentious. For

instance, the recent Independent Local Government Review

Panel3 observed that ‘changes to the rating system and rate-

pegging are essential to generate the revenues needed to fund

infrastructure and services, and – equally as important – to make

the system more equitable.’ The NSW Government promised to

conduct a review of the rating system in response to the ILGRP

recommendations. However, rate-capping has considerable

populist appeal in Australia, as evidenced in the recent South

Australian and Victorian state elections. It is thus important to

empirically investigate the effects of rate-capping. Accordingly,

1 Brian Dollery, Suzanne O’Keefe and Lin Crase, ‘State Oversight

Models for Australian Local Government’ (2010) 28 Economic Papers

279, 290.

2 Judy Temple, ‘Community Composition and Voter Support for Tax

Limitations: Evidence from Home-rule Elections’ (1996) 62 Southern

Economic Journal 1002, 1016; Robert Hay and Steve Martin,

‘Controlling Local Government Spending: The Implementation and

Impact of Capping Council Taxes’ (2014) 40 Local Government

Studies 224, 239.

3 Independent Local Government Review Panel (ILGRP), Revitalising

Local Government (2013).

140

JOURNAL OF AUSTRALIAN TAXATION

J DREW & B DOLLERY

in this paper we analyse the likely impact of rate-pegging on

Victorian local government.

Following the electoral victory of the Australian Labor Party

(ALP) in Victoria in late 2014, the new Minister for Local

Government Natalie Hutchins announced that rate-capping -

linked to the Consumer Price Index (CPI) - will be introduced into

Victorian local government from the 2016/17 fiscal year onwards.

Victorian Premier Daniel Andrews (2014) justified the

introduction of rate-pegging on grounds that ‘councils will be

forced to limit rate rises and detail where every dollar will be

spent, because ratepayers deserve a fair go’, adding that ‘this

policy also sends a clear message that we expect councils to keep

their rates in line with CPI’.4

The timing of the Victorian Government’s foray into rate-

capping is not propitious. Not only has the Commonwealth

Government announced a three-year freeze on Financial

Assistance Grants (which represent a significant proportion of

Victorian municipal income), but Victorian councils have also

been subjected to defined benefit superannuation imposts in the

order of half a billion dollars over the past few years5.

Accordingly, if the Victorian Government proceeds with its plan

to cap rates – starting from the 2016/17 financial year – one (or

more) of three responses must occur (in the absence of an increase

in funding from higher tiers of government): (a) additional debt

must be incurred; (b) local services must diminish; or (c)

operational efficiency must increase. Against this background, in

this paper we examine empirically the likely impact of rate-

capping on Victorian local government in terms of equity

considerations, financial sustainability and municipal efficiency.

4 John Masanauskas and Christopher Gillett, ‘Labor’s Plan to Curb

Council Rates’ Herald Sun (Melbourne) 3 May 2014.

5 Municipal Association of Victoria (MAV), Defined Benefits

Taskforce – Final Report (2012).

(2015) 17(1)

141

RATE CAPPING IN LOCAL GOVERNMENT

The paper is divided into nine main parts. Section 2 provides

a synoptic review of rate-capping and the debate on its merits in

NSW. Section 3 outlines theoretical approaches to the analysis of

rate-pegging whilst Section 4 provides a brief summary of the

extant literature. Section 5 assesses the equity claims underlying

property tax limitations, Section 6 examines sustainability claims

for rate-pegging with respect to debt and infrastructure, and

Section 7 evaluates the efficiency claims for rate-capping. Section

8 considers various alternative methods of addressing problems

in local government identified by the application of personal

finance theory and agency theory. The paper concludes in section

9 with a brief discussion of the policy implications of the

empirical analysis.

2. RATE-CAPPING

Rate-pegging represents a sub-set of a larger category of

public sector regulation dealing with state-imposed limitations on

expenditure and taxation by local authorities, including property

taxes.6 Regulation of this kind has spawned a theoretical and

empirical literature with an overwhelming American institutional

focus7, largely since state-wide limitations on local taxes, fees and

charges, including property taxes, are relatively common in the

United States, often deriving from referenda.8 In addition to this

6 Temple, above n 2; Nathan Anderson, ‘Property Tax Limitations: An

Interpretive Review’ (2006) 59 National Tax Journal 685, 694.

7 See, for example, Mathew McCubbins and Ellen Moule, ‘Making

Mountains of Debt Out of Molehills: The Pro-Cyclical Implications of

Tax and Expenditure Limitations’ (2010) 63 National Tax Journal

603, 622; Daniel Mullins and Bruce Wallin, ‘Tax and Expenditure

Limitation: Introduction and Overview’ (2004) 24 Public Budgeting &

Finance 1, 14.

8 See, for example, David Figlio and Arthur O’Sullivan ‘The Local

Response to Tax Limitation Measures: Do Local Government

Manipulate Voters to Increase Revenues?’ (2001) 44 Journal of Law

and Economics 233, 257.

142

JOURNAL OF AUSTRALIAN TAXATION

J DREW & B DOLLERY

American literature, some scholarly work has been undertaken on

tax limitations in local government in other parts of the world,

including Europe9 and Australia.10

The economic rationale for rate-pegging is straightforward:

local government typically holds a monopoly in providing local

services. As a result, local councils can deliver these services at

excessive prices and/or inefficiently, thereby justifying regulation

by higher levels of government aimed at the efficient and

equitable provision of local services.11 Regulation of this kind

generally has two main objectives. Firstly, in terms of economic

efficiency, optimal regulation should strive to achieve (a)

allocative efficiency, where local community preferences should

be reflected in the range of local services, and (b) productive

efficiency, where local services should be delivered at least-cost.

Secondly, policy intervention regulation also should aim at equity

objectives, such as ensuring essential local services are provided

to all households at reasonable prices.

Effective regulation is notoriously difficult to implement,

including in local government.12 In the municipal realm,

intervention is further complicated since councils possess

taxation powers, absent in the private sector and most public

utilities. Finally, rate-pegging poses particular problems since

regulatory intervention does not target particular local services

9 Robin Boadway and Anwar Shah, Fiscal Federalism: Principles and

Practice of Multi-order Governance (Cambridge University Press,

2009); Jens Blom-Hansen, Martin Bækgaard and Soren Serritzlew,

‘Tax Limitations and Revenue Shifting Strategies in Local

Government’ (2014) 34 Public Budgeting & Finance 64, 84.

10 Brian Dollery and Albert Wijeweera, ‘Time for Change? An

Assessment of Rate-Pegging in New South Wales Local Government’

(2010) 6 Commonwealth Journal of Local Governance 56, 76.

11 Stephen Bailey, Public Sector Economics (Macmillan, 1995).

12 Ayre Hillman, Public Finance and Public Policy (Cambridge

University Press, 2005).

(2015) 17(1)

143

RATE CAPPING IN LOCAL GOVERNMENT

but instead the ‘tax-price’ of a basket of local public services

(which are mostly unpriced).

In NSW local government, the Independent Pricing and

Regulation Tribunal13 has identified four arguments in favour of

rate-pegging. In the first place, rate-pegging ‘prevents the abuse

of monopoly power’ in the provision of basic local services. In

addition, proponents contend it limits the ‘provision of non-core

services and infrastructure that might prove unsustainable to

ratepayers’. Furthermore, rate-capping may reduce ‘the risk of

poor governance in the local government sector’. Finally, it is

argued rate-pegging ‘limits the ability of councils to divert funds

from essential infrastructure to other projects’, especially outlays

on ‘marginal services’ better provided by private firms.

Two additional arguments for rate-pegging were advanced in

the Independent Inquiry into the Financial Sustainability of NSW

Local Government.14 Firstly, compared with other Australian

local government systems, NSW rate-pegging had been effective

in its primary aim of restraining increases in rates. Secondly, rate-

pegging had obliged NSW councils to become more efficient,

especially in limiting overheads and administrative costs.

Dollery, Crase and Byrnes15 proposed a public choice case for

rate-capping in Australian local government. Drawing on

Wittman16, they argued that the ubiquity of ‘local government

failure’ in Australia had simulated a demand by ratepayers for

strict regulatory oversight of councils by state regulatory

13 Independent Pricing and Regulatory Authority (IPART), Revenue

Framework for Local Government (2009) 55.

14 Local Government and Shires Association (LGSA), Are Councils

Sustainable?, Final Report: Findings and Recommendations (2006).

15 Brian Dollery, Lin Crase and Joel Byrnes, ‘Local Government

Failure: Why Does Australian Local Government Experience

Permanent Financial Austerity?’ (2006) 41 Australian Journal of

Political Science 339, 353.

16 Donald Witman, The Myth of Democratic Failure: Why Political

Institutions are Efficient (University of Chicago Press, 1995).

144

JOURNAL OF AUSTRALIAN TAXATION

J DREW & B DOLLERY

agencies, especially in financial matters. Accordingly, in NSW

rate-capping, ‘“watchdog” institutions will form an agency

relationship with local government voters to demystify fiscal

illusion by monitoring council revenue and expenditure decisions

on behalf of voters’.17

However, rate-pegging in NSW has also come under sharp

criticism. For example, IPART18 has pinpointed four lines of

attack: it ‘limits councils’ capacity to provide local services, it

prevents ‘infrastructure backlogs from being addressed’, it has

caused municipalities to impose ‘higher user pays charges which

could result in pricing inequities, and it runs counter to ‘local

democracy’.

The NSW Local Government and Shires Association19 – now

known as Local Government NSW – proposed a more general

argument against rate-pegging. In particular, rate-capping has

created ‘public expectations about maximum rate increases,

placing political pressure on councils to stay within the limit and

not seek special variations’. Similarly, rate-pegging enables NSW

local councils to engage in politically expedient ‘blame shifting’

onto the NSW Government. In particular, rate-capping offers

political ‘default option’ since all rate increases can be attributed

to the NSW Government agencies, community consultation is

avoided, and local authorities can ‘blame the state government for

their financial deficiencies’. It is claimed that these factors have

given rise to the ‘under-provision of community infrastructure

and services’ and a substantial local infrastructure backlog.

3. THEORETICAL PERSPECTIVES

17 Dollery, Crase and Byrnes, above n 15.

18 Independent Pricing and Regulatory Authority, above n 13.

19 Local Government and Shires Association of NSW, Submission to

the Independent Pricing and Regulatory Tribunal of NSW’s Review of

Revenue Framework for Local Government (2008) 14.

(2015) 17(1)

145

RATE CAPPING IN LOCAL GOVERNMENT

Two conceptual approaches have been developed to explain

property tax limitations through rate-capping. In the first place,

agency theory20 holds that residents (as principals) are wary of

‘agency failure’ by local authorities (as agents), which could

result in excess expenditure above socially optimal levels. In most

Australian local government systems, councillors are typically

elected every four years, thereby providing residents with an

opportunity to remove elected officials if they believe these

persons are not representing their interests, although it might be

noted that the limited number of prospective candidates are

generally drawn from a small group of special interest parties. In

fact, in the last Victorian local government elections 26

councillors were returned unopposed.21

However, this political mechanism offers only limited

recourse given that (a) lengthy periods occur between elections

(b) high information costs may mean that residents are unaware

of excessive/unwarranted outlays and (c) ‘candidates come as

bundles, so that incumbents might be able to spend more and

maintain their position if they satisfy people’s views along other

dimensions’.22 Following agency theory, residents may seek state

government intervention through rate-caps to limit agency failure

by local councils.23

Secondly, ‘personal finance theory’24 holds that local

residents judge the value of local services received from

20 Michael Jensen and William Meckling, ‘Theory of the Firm:

Managerial Behaviour, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure’ (1976)

3 Journal of Financial Economics 305, 360.

21 Joseph Drew and Brian Dollery, ‘The Price of democracy? Political

Representation Structure and Per Capita Expenditure in Victorian

Local Government’ (2016) In Print Urban Affairs Review, DOI:

10.1332/030557316x14539914690045.

22 David Cutler, Douglas Elmendorf and Richard Zeckhauser,

‘Restraining the Leviathan: Property Tax Limitation in Massachusetts’

(1999) 71 Journal of Public Economics 313, 334.

23 Dollery, Crase and Byrnes, above n 15.

24 Cutler, Elmendorf and Zeckhauser, above n 22.

146

JOURNAL OF AUSTRALIAN TAXATION

J DREW & B DOLLERY

municipalities according to their local government tax burden.

Following this approach, the higher the perceived rate of property

tax, the more likely it is that a resident will support rate-capping.

In addition, significant increases to property taxes predispose

individuals to support rate-pegs. This line of reasoning is

particularly relevant to Australian local government given that

municipal rates are highly visible through quarterly rate bills sent

to residents by councils. An embryonic empirical literature offers

some support for this approach in the American municipal

milieu.25

Both of these perceptions are problematic since both presume

rate-pegging inevitably limits rate increases. However, this is not

necessarily the case: individual tax liabilities may still rise

significantly as a result of a rezoning of land use, new property

valuations in excess of the average valuation for the municipality,

or (as in NSW) as a result of a Special Rate Variation (SRV)

enabling rate increases in excess of the cap.

Unfortunately, to date there has been no attempt to

empirically analyse these questions in the Australian local

government context. Accordingly, we seek to address this gap in

the literature. In addition, a second aim of our paper is to address

the common misconception that rate-caps are the only reliable

method of addressing the potential abuse of monopoly power in

the local government. We show that viable alternative policy

approaches exist.

The empirical comparison of the only fully-fledged rate-cap

regime in NSW with existing Victorian municipal data

undertaken in this paper can provide an insight into the likely

response to the Victorian state government proposal.

25 Ibid.

(2015) 17(1)

147

RATE CAPPING IN LOCAL GOVERNMENT

4. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON TAX LIMITATIONS

While comparatively little is known about the effects of

expenditure and tax constraints on local government, the

empirical literature has shown that these measures can have

substantial unanticipated effects.26 Thus Temple27 found evidence

which suggested that state-wide limits on property taxes induced

a relatively larger reduction in local services than local

administration. Similarly, Vigdor28 held that tax limitations

succeed because they allowed voters to lower tax rates in local

communities other than their own where they hold property,

invest or work, but have no vote.

Two findings in the empirical literature have significance for

Australian debates over rate-pegging. In the first place, property

tax limitations often induce local authorities to increase income

from other revenue sources. For instance, in a study of 29

American states, Shadbegian29 found many local councils shifted

income away from property taxes toward ‘miscellaneous

revenue’. Skidmore30 found similar results in his analysis of 49

American states. In their US study, Kouser, McCubbins, and

26 Mark Skidmore, ‘Tax and Expenditure Limitations and the Fiscal

Relationships between State and Local Governments’ (1999) 99 Public

Choice 77, 102; Thad Kousser, Mathew McCubbins and Ellen Moule,

‘For Whom the TEL Tolls: Can State Tax and Expenditure Limits

Effectively Reduce Spending?’ (2008) 8 State Politics and Policy

Quarterly 331, 361; Suho Bae, Seong-gin Moon and Changhoon Jung,

‘Economic Effects of State-Level Tax and Expenditure Limitations’

(2012) 72 Public Administration Review 649, 658.

27 Temple, above n 2.

28 Jacob Vigdor, ‘Other People's Taxes: Non-resident Voters and State-

wide Limitation of Local Government’ (2004) 47 Journal of Law and

Economics 453, 476.

29 Ronald Shadbegian, ‘The Effect of Tax and Expenditure Limitation

on the Revenue Structure of Local Government, 1962–87’ (1999) 55

National Tax Journal 221, 237.

30 Skidmore, above n 26.

148

JOURNAL OF AUSTRALIAN TAXATION

J DREW & B DOLLERY

Moule31 established that most states increased charges and fees

following the introduction of tax limitations. In an analogous

vein, Mullins and Joyce32 examined 48 American states from

1970 to 1990 concluding that while tax limitations reduced local

taxes, these reductions were offset by increases in fees and

charges. In an analysis based on 1,400 American municipalities,

Preston and Ichniowski33 demonstrated that revenue limits

decreased property tax revenue but increase ‘other revenue’.

Secondly, available empirical evidence suggests that the

impact of tax limitations is not uniform across local authorities

and depends instead on the characteristics of local councils. For

instance, Brown34 found that in Colorado local government the

effects of limitations depended on council size and were more

potent in small councils. Similarly, Mullins35 established that

limitations were most effective in poor municipalities.

5. INTER-MUNICIPAL REVENUE EFFORT EQUITY

Residential tax effort measures the proportion of residential

rates paid as a percentage of the total annual incomes accruing to

residents in a given local government area. This is the most

relevant measure of inter-municipal equity given that ‘all taxes

31 Kousser, McCubbins and Moule, above n 26.

32 Daniel Mullins and Philip Joyce, ‘Tax and Expenditure Limitations

and State and Local Fiscal Structure: An Empirical Assessment’

(1996) Spring Public Budgeting & Finance 75, 102.

33 Anne Preston and Casey Ichniowski, ‘A National Perspective on the

Nature and Effects of the Local Property Tax Revolt, 1976–1966’

(1991) 44 National Tax Journal 123, 145.

34 Tom Brown, ‘Constitutional Tax and Expenditure Limitation in

Colorado: The Impact on Municipal Governments’ (2000) 20 Public

Budgeting & Finance 29, 50.

35 Daniel Mullins, ‘Tax and Expenditure Limitations and the Fiscal

Response of Local Government: Asymmetric Intra-Local Fiscal

Effects’ (2004) 24 Public Budgeting & Finance 111, 147.

(2015) 17(1)

149

RATE CAPPING IN LOCAL GOVERNMENT

levied by the city would ultimately be paid from the income of

the city residents regardless of the mix of taxes actually used’.36

The data for residential tax impost was obtained directly from the

notes to the Income Statement of individual NSW and Victorian

councils and includes general rates as well as fees and charges for

council services. It is important to include fees and charges in tax

impost data given that the empirical evidence from abroad

suggests that municipalities ‘game’ rate-caps by increasing the

fees and charges not subject to regulation.37 Total annual income

accruing to people residing in a given local government area was

obtained from the latest data i.e. the 2012 National Regional

Profile38: alterations were made to the data by including a

synthetic estimate of Commonwealth welfare payments and

excluding unincorporated business income.39 Residential tax

effort was calculated by dividing the total residential tax impost

for each council by the total income accruing to individuals

residing in the respective council.

Table 1 contains measures of the range and central tendency

of local council residential revenue effort for NSW and Victoria

as well as a comparison stratified according to urban and rural

categorisation (informed by the Australian Classification of Local

Government (ACLG) scheme). A number of noteworthy points

arise from the data. Firstly, the tax impost placed on residential

36 See Helen Ladd and John Yinger, America’s Ailing Cities – Fiscal

Health and the Design of Urban Policy (John Hopkins University

Press, 1989); Joseph Drew and Brian Dollery, ‘A Fair Go? A Response

to the Independent Local Government Review Panel’s Assessment of

Municipal Taxation in New South Wales’ (2015) 30 Australian Tax

Forum 471.

37 Blom-Hansen, Baekgaard, and Serritzlew, above n 9.

38 Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS), National Regional Profile

(2014).

39 Quantum of welfare payments is not available on the ABS National

Regional Profile. An estimate of the quantum was made by

multiplying the number of recipients in each welfare payment category

by the appropriate rate of welfare payment.

150

JOURNAL OF AUSTRALIAN TAXATION

J DREW & B DOLLERY

ratepayers is remarkably modest even when one considers the

limited remit of Australian local government. In most cases, rates

are a fraction of the personal income tax paid by individuals.40 It

is thus surprising that rate-pegging enjoys so much popular

support. However, as noted earlier, the ‘visibility’ of rates

compared with other forms of taxation, such as salary deductions,

may be part of the reason (see also, Section 8 below).

Secondly, Table 1 provides evidence which suggests that the

almost four decade-long rate cap regime in NSW may have been

successful in limiting the tax burden on ratepayers. Finally, the

evidence seems to support the ILGRP’s41 claim that rate-capping

has reduced inter-municipal equity, as demonstrated by the fact

that the range of rate effort in NSW is considerably larger than

Victoria, which is particularly evident in the stratified summary.

Moreover, the standard deviation – which measures the average

‘scatter’ of individual councils with respect to the mean – is

relatively high and suggests quite a lot of variation within each

strata.

Inter-municipal inequity seems to be an unavoidable

consequence of any long-term rate-cap regime. This is because

rate-caps are applied in a compound fashion to rate levels existing

in the base year. If inequity exists in the base year, then the equity

gap will be exacerbated through time. Moreover, if demographic

patterns change as a result of urban sprawl or changes to local

economies, then inter-municipal inequity must follow in the

absence of SRV. The ILGRP42 cited the incongruity of average

rates of $484 in affluent North Sydney when compared with the

average residential rates of $957 in the more modest Penrith as a

40 In fact, local government rates represent only 3.4% of total tax

revenue collected by the various tiers of Australian government;

Australian Bureau of Statistics ‘Government Finance Statistics 2013-

14’.

41 Independent Local Government Review Panel, above n 3.

42 Ibid.

(2015) 17(1)

151

RATE CAPPING IN LOCAL GOVERNMENT

specific example of the inequity which can result from almost

forty years of rate-pegging.

Table 1: Revenue Effort Equity NSW and Victoria, 2012

(%)

Smallest Largest Median Mean Standard

Deviation

NSW

0.61

3.30

1.39

1.39

0.51

(State)

Victoria 0.91

2.62

1.75

1.74

0.39

(State)

NSW

0.61

3.30

1.521

1.58

0.48

Urban

Victoria 0.91

2.62

1.69

1.69

0.38

Urban

NSW

0.33

2.37

1.12

1.17

0.44

Rural

Victoria 1.1

2.57

1.84

1.88

0.38

Rural

6. MUNICIPAL SUSTAINABILITY

We examined two claims regarding the deleterious effects of

rate-capping on financial sustainability: (a) that rate-pegging

increases debt and (b) that rate-pegging reduces investment in

infrastructure. Both claims follow from the proposition that - in

the absence of increases in revenue from higher tiers of

government - rate-capping will probably result in lower levels

and/or quality of local services or higher debt loads. In the latter

case this also raises problems of intergenerational inequity.

Table 2 presents data for local government liabilities per

household for each council jurisdiction over the period 2009-

2013 inclusive (inflated by CPI to 2013 dollars). Total liability

data was extracted from the balance sheets of each council in the

relevant jurisdiction, while household data was extracted from the

152

JOURNAL OF AUSTRALIAN TAXATION

J DREW & B DOLLERY

Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) census data of number of

households in NSW and Victoria, adjusted by the annual ABS

Buildings Approval data. Liabilities were expressed per

household in response to Drew and Dollery43 who argued that

households – rather than population per se – are the optimal

functional unit for empirical analysis in addition to being a more

reliable and less volatile measure of council size (particularly in

inter-census periods).

It is clear from Table 2 that municipal debt in NSW is far

greater than Victoria. In fact, as at 2013 (the limit of ABS housing

data), NSW councils carried around 70% more debt than their

Victorian counterparts. Victorian municipal debt rose by an

alarming rate in 2012, with only slight moderation in 2013.

However, this can largely attributed to liabilities of about

$250/household which were incurred by Victorian councils as a

result of the defined benefits superannuation impost during this

period.44

Table 2: Liabilities per Household, NSW and Victoria 2009-

2013 ($’000)

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

NSW liabilities

2.219 2.439

2.320

2.340

2.404

per household#

Victoria

1.095 1.148

1.193

1.489

1.396

liabilities per

household#

# all figures have been inflated to 2013 dollars.

43 Joseph Drew and Brian Dollery, ‘Keeping It In-House – Households

as an Alternative Proxy for Local Government Output’ (2014) 73

Australian Journal of Public Administration 235, 246.

44 Municipal Association of Victoria, above n 5.

(2015) 17(1)

153

RATE CAPPING IN LOCAL GOVERNMENT

Table 3 provides statistics on the average infrastructure

renewal45 ratio published by the regulatory authorities in NSW

and Victoria. It is important to note that the two ratios are not

directly comparable since each jurisdiction employs a different

measure for the quantum of assets consumed (i.e. the denominator

of the ratios): NSW uses depreciation accruals for the period

whereas Victoria employs current replacement cost (as new)

divided by useful life. Both use the quantum of asset renewals as

the numerator of the ratio and both have employed consistent

methodology over the period 2009-2012. Accordingly,

conclusions can be drawn by comparing the change in

infrastructure renewals over the four-year period. In this regard,

it appears that NSW councils have reduced infrastructure renewal

since 2009, while Victorian councils have held asset renewal at a

constant level for most of this period. However, some caution

needs to be exercised in judging progress on infrastructure

renewals given that both ratios employ estimates as the ratio

denominator.

45 Infrastructure renewals are defined as spending on existing

infrastructure assets which return same to original service potential.

154

JOURNAL OF AUSTRALIAN TAXATION

J DREW & B DOLLERY

Table 3: Infrastructure Renewal, NSW and Victoria 2009-

2012

2009

2010

2011

2012

Mean Infrastructure

1.028 1.000

0.665

0.8088

Renewals NSW

Change from 2009

-

-

-

2.74%

35.32%

21.32%

Average change in

-

-

14.39%

Infrastructure

2.14%

33.49%

Renewal from

previous year

Avg Change in Infra

-

Renewal since 2009

21.24%

Mean Infrastructure

0.78

0.75

0.77

1.09

Renewals Victoria

Change in Average

-

-1.31%

38.95%

from 2009

4.27%

Average change in

-

2.32%

31.57%

Infrastructure

3.35%

Renewal from

previous year

Average change in

30.55%

Infrastructure

Renewal since 2009

We now test the final claim regarding rate-capping:

restricting rate revenue imposes financial discipline on municipal

behaviour thereby increasing council efficiency.

7. MUNICIPAL EFFICIENCY

In economics, technical efficiency measures the conversion

of inputs into outputs in production processes. This is best

assessed using the sophisticated technique of locally inter-

temporal data envelopment analysis which accommodates

(2015) 17(1)

155

RATE CAPPING IN LOCAL GOVERNMENT

multiple inputs (generally specified as capital and labour costs)

and multiple outputs (best specified as length of municipal roads,

number of households and number of employing businesses).46

However, this technical type of analysis is beyond the scope of a

policy orientated article and we have thus decided to proxy

efficiency using expenditure per household (it should be noted

that the NSW government uses expenditure per capita to measure

local government efficiency47). In our analysis there is thus a

single input of operating expenditure and a single output proxied

by the total number of households in the jurisdiction.

Table 4 outlines the results from our analysis of expenditure

per household over the period 2009-2013. Total expenditure data

(less depreciation)48 was extracted from the audited financial

statements of each council within the NSW and Victoria local

government systems. We have again used households as the

proxy for local government output in response to empirical

evidence regarding its functional compatibility, high reliability

and low volatility49. The data in Table 4 does not provide any

conclusive evidence of a statistically significant difference in

efficiency between the two jurisdictions: NSW has slightly lower

expenditure per household from 2009 to 2012, but higher

46 Drew, Kortt and Dollery conduct a thorough analysis of the effect of

various DEA specifications on efficiency analysis and interested

readers are thus directed to: Joseph Drew, Michael Kortt and Brian

Dollery, ‘No Aladdin’s Cave in New South Wales? Local Government

Amalgamation, Scale Economies and Data Envelopment Specification’

DOI: 10.1177/0095399715581045 Administration & Society 1, 21.

47 Office of Local Government, Time series Data 2011/12 – 2013/14

(2015).

48 Depreciation has been excluded in response to many studies which

demonstrate that municipal officials regularly manipulate this accrual

item to manage earnings. Studies demonstrating this include: Joseph

Drew and Brian Dollery, ‘Inconsistent Depreciation Practice and

Public Policymaking: Local Government Reform in New South Wales’

(2015) 25 Australian Accounting Review 28, 37.

49 Drew and Dollery, above n 43.

156

JOURNAL OF AUSTRALIAN TAXATION

J DREW & B DOLLERY

expenditure per household in the final year under analysis.

Moreover, we need to be mindful that this is an approximation of

‘technical efficiency’.50 We conducted locally inter-temporal data

envelopment analysis (DEA) for all councils in the two

jurisdictions. Our analysis suggested slightly higher average

municipal efficiency for Victorian councils. Results are available

from the corresponding author. However, the important thing to

note is that there is no conclusive evidence to support the claim

made by proponents of rate-capping that it enhances municipal

efficiency.

Table 4: Expenditure per Household, NSW and Victoria

2009-2013 ($’000)

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

NSW

2.605 2.723

2.810

2.944

3.033

expenditure per

household#

Victoria

2.703 2.815

2.902

3.170

3.024

expenditure per

household#

# all figures have been inflated to 2013 dollars. Expenditure

excludes depreciation.

8. ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES TO PROBLEM

Perhaps the greatest misconception regarding rate-capping is

that it is the only feasible public policy instrument for addressing

the potential excesses of municipal monopoly power. In fact,

50 The authors have in fact conducted locally inter-temporal data

envelopment analysis (DEA) for all councils in the two jurisdictions.

This analysis suggests slightly higher average municipal efficiency for

Victorian councils. Results are available from the corresponding

author.

(2015) 17(1)

157

RATE CAPPING IN LOCAL GOVERNMENT

superior alternative strategies exist.51 In general, policies to limit

monopoly excesses fall broadly under two categories which

respond to the two theoretical positions outlined in Section 3 of

this paper. Moreover, in terms of political realities, it is important

to note that alternatives to rate-pegging are just as critical for

NSW policymakers as they are for their Victorian counterparts,

given that there is a strong possibility that NSW rates will spike

if rate-caps are removed.

As we observed earlier, personal finance theory hinges on the

perceived value of local services relative to the tax burden

imposed.52 In Australia, the value of municipal services far

exceeds the local government tax impost, given substantial

federal government Financial Assistance Grants (FAGs)

(typically accounting for around one tenth of municipal

revenue).53 However, it is the perception of ratepayers not fact

which is the critical point under this theoretical approach.

One way to reduce the demand for rate-caps would be to

increase FAGs. However, this is most unlikely given the recent

freeze on FAGs for a period of three years.54 Furthermore, much

more can be done with respect to intergovernmental fiscal

relations. Firstly, there is a need for fairer distribution of FAGs so

that the horizontal fiscal equity principle embodied in legislation

- but absent in practice - is enforced. In this regard, Drew and

Dollery55 have demonstrated a failure by state Local Government

51 Patricia Florestano, ‘Revenue-Raising Limitations on Local

Government: A Focus on Alternative Responses’ (1981) 41 Public

Administration Review 122, 131.

52 Cutler, Elmendorf and Zeckhauser, above n 22.

53 The 2014-15 total Commonwealth financial assistance grants for

NSW and Victoria were $715.7m and $541.7 m respectively.

54 Keith Rhoades, ‘Abandon Grant Freeze or Communities Lose Out’,

Local Government Association New South Wales (Sydney) 18 May,

2014.

55 Joseph Drew and Brian Dollery, ‘Road to Ruin? Consistency,

Transparency and Horizontal Equalisation of Road Grant Allocations

158

JOURNAL OF AUSTRALIAN TAXATION

J DREW & B DOLLERY

Grant Commissions to allocate financial assistance grants in

accordance with the principles of the enabling legislation.

Secondly, there is a need for greater clarity surrounding the

sources of council funding. For example, residential rate notices

could clearly state the source and level of council service

subsidies. If residents are more aware of the quantum of local

government grant revenue, they may reassess their local tax

burden against value received. Thirdly, the fiscal imbalance

which characterises the Australian federation could be addressed

to provide local government sufficient and secure revenue to fund

the services it provides.56 Intergovernmental grants are just one

way to address fiscal imbalance. Other options include new tax

bases or quarantining taxes by higher tiers of government for

councils (similar to how the GST is collected by the federal

government for state governments).57

Finally, cost-shifting - wherein new mandates are forced on

local government with only partial funding by the higher tiers of

government previously responsible for provision – must be

addressed,58 if residents are to accurately appraise value relative

to cost for local services.

Perceptions of the value of local services relative to the tax

burden can also be enhanced through ensuring that the cost of

specific services is met by the parties receiving the benefit

in Eastern Mainland Australian States’ (2015) 39 Public

Administration Quarterly 517, 545.

56 Wallace Oates, ‘An Essay on Fiscal Federalism’ (1999) XXXVII

Journal of Economic Literature 1120, 1149.

57 Indeed under the Fraser government’s Local Government (Personal

Income Tax Sharing) Act 1976 (CTH) councils were to be allocated a

fixed percentage (2.00% in 1981) of Commonwealth personal income

tax collections. This approach provided secure and expanding sources

of revenue for councils as a way of redress the vertical fiscal

imbalance present in the Australian federation.

58 Brian Dollery, Lin Crase and Andrew Johnson, Australian Local

Government Economics (UNSW Press, 2006).

(2015) 17(1)

159

RATE CAPPING IN LOCAL GOVERNMENT

through more user charges,59 as well as timing rate increases to

remove periodic sharp rises. By ensuring that those who receive

the benefit pay the costs associated with the service wherever

practicable, residents can gain a more accurate perception of

value of the municipal burden. This strategy obviously cannot be

applied to pure public goods which are both non-rival and non-

excludable (such as local roads and pavements), which must be

met through rates. However, for some services, such as garbage

collection, development applications, and public health and safety

inspections, people receiving benefits could pay user fees and

charges which would more accurately reflect the cost of

provision.60

Unfortunately, the regulation of fees and charges – by IPART

in NSW and analogous bodies in other states – as well as the

failure of municipal accounting systems to accurately assess the

costs of services (particularly with respect to allocating indirect

costs and depreciation), has meant that full cost recovery rarely

occurs.61 The inevitable result is the cross-subsidisation of service

provision by ratepayers. While for merit goods this practice might

be defensible, merit goods typically represent only a small subset

of the local services provided by local councils. Moreover, where

services are subsidised, it is important that donors and recipients

59 James Buchanan, ‘Federalism and Fiscal Equity’ (1950) 40 The

American Economic Review 583, 599.

60 We recognise that fees are charged for many local government

services. However, it is not at all certain that fees are levied on a full

cost recovery basis; see, for instance, Judith McNeill and Brian

Dollery, ‘Calculating Developer Charges for Urban Infrastructure: A

Feasible Method for Applying Marginal Cost Pricing’ (2003) 48 The

Engineering Economist 218, 240.

61 Garry Carnegie and Brian West, ‘A Conceptual Analysis of Price

Setting in Australian Local Government’ (2010) 53 Australian

Accounting Review 110, 120; Garry Carnegie, Jacqueline Tuck and

Brian West, ‘Price Setting Practices in Australian Local Government’

(2011) 57 Australian Accounting Review 193, 201.

160

JOURNAL OF AUSTRALIAN TAXATION

J DREW & B DOLLERY

of the subsidy alike are advised on both the quantum and

reasoning involved.62

Perceptions of value can also be enhanced by removing

‘lumpy’ rate rises. This requires both a higher degree of strategic

planning, as well as the flexibility to increase rates on a more

frequent basis. Strategic planning which accurately assesses

municipal obligations five years or more into the future allows for

a measured increase in rates and avoids ‘rate shocks’. Similarly,

the ability to increase rates on a quarterly basis consonant with

the quarterly nature of rate invoices – rather than the current

annual practice – means that councils can respond quickly to

unexpected obligations and introduce rate increases over a longer

time period, thus avoiding sudden significant rate rises.

Finally, enhancing the actual value of local services can also

help to address public concerns underpinning rate-capping. This

can be achieved by decreasing the cost of municipal debt,

reducing the perceived municipal tax impost on residents, and

removing the legislative power of councils to levy charges for

goods and services which are not used or wanted. For instance,

Dollery, Kortt and Grant63 have demonstrated that the

establishment of a national local government infrastructure

finance authority would facilitate cheaper and more flexible

access to capital for local infrastructure investment and renewal.64

A second option would focus on eliminating the wide range of

rate exemptions which currently exist for state and federal

government commercial activities, religious and benevolent

foundations, select agricultural ventures (such oyster farming and

62 Carnegie and West, above n 61.

63 Brian Dollery, Michael Kortt and Bligh Grant, ‘Harnessing Private

Funds to Alleviate the Australian Local Government Infrastructure

Backlog’ (2012) 31 Economic Papers 114, 122.

64 Ibid.

(2015) 17(1)

161

RATE CAPPING IN LOCAL GOVERNMENT

cattle dipping) and commercial sporting facilities (like the

Sydney Cricket Ground).65

Finally, removing the legislated power of councils to charge

fees for services not actually used would reduce the coercive

council monopoly power. For example, the current ability for

councils to levy a base water charge where a water line runs past

a vacant property, irrespective of whether the property is actually

connected, should be removed.

In contrast to the personal finance approach, agency theory

rests on the trust between residents (as principals) and municipal

officials (as agents) that the latter behave in a financially prudent

manner. Residents may have good reason to mistrust municipal

officials in view of various allegations of waste, excess,

corruption and pork-barrelling.66 Thus the exercise of greater

prudence in council spending is clearly an avenue to reduce calls

for tax limitations. Moreover, measures which reduce the

information costs for residents to monitor municipal officials or

enhance the opportunities for residents to sanction officials might

reduce the need for rate-caps.

With respect to a reduction in information costs, existing

practice in both NSW and Victoria involves the compilation of

comparative data published on an annual basis. This has obvious

merit,67 although the data currently disseminated – focussing

mainly on average levels of rates, financial ratio data and

expenditure according to functional categories – is generalised

and does not inform residents about the cost of specific projects

or where waste might be occurring. Moreover, in the absence of

65 Independent Local Government Review Panel, above n 3.

66 See, for example, A Current Affair ‘Council Spending Sprees’ Nine

MSN July 6, 2015. For evidence of pork-barrelling see Drew and

Dollery, above n 21.

67 See, for instance, Office of Local Government, Comparative

Information on NSW Local Government 2012/13 (2014); Department

of Transport Planning and Local Infrastructure, Source Data 2005-

2012 (2012).

162

JOURNAL OF AUSTRALIAN TAXATION

J DREW & B DOLLERY

data relating the number and quality of outputs for each functional

category, accurate comparisons between councils is all but

impossible. This could be addressed through an addendum to the

existing reports providing a higher degree of disaggregation, and

this in addition to details of the number and quality of outputs,

would increase the information value of these reports.

However, it is far from clear that the majority of residents are

aware that comparative data is available, let alone consulting this

data. There would thus seem to be a good argument that a

summary report of inter-temporal functional expenditure trends

should be included with the rate assessment notices issued

annually. Providing a report direct to residents further reduces

information costs as well as ensuring awareness of the existence

of comparative data. Moreover, detailed information of the cost

of specific programs – rather than broad functional categories

such as ‘recreation’ – is currently not available even in the annual

audited financial statements, but it is required if residents are to

closely monitor council expenditure. It could be argued that this

sort of detailed information should be available to residents

wishing to inquire into the costs of specific programs, although,

it appears that council accounting information systems would

need to be improved for this to occur.68 Finally, there is a good

case for requiring councils - perhaps by legislation - to provide

accurate costings for proposals to introduce new services. Ideally

these costings should be made available to residents prior to the

council meeting dedicated to considering the proposal.

Even if residents are able to get detailed information on fiscal

prudence, there are limited opportunities to apply sanctions. For

example, in both NSW and Victoria elections occur on a

quaternary basis – a considerable time before a political sanction

can be applied. A partial solution would be to increase the

frequency of elections, perhaps reducing the term to three years

consistent with Commonwealth government elections. Moreover,

68 Carnegie, Tuck and West, above n 61.

(2015) 17(1)

163

RATE CAPPING IN LOCAL GOVERNMENT

council officers are not subject to political sanction and political

representatives are assessed on a bundle of attributes.69 Penalties

for councillor misconduct provided for under the respective state

local government acts seem inadequate: in NSW the maximum

penalty for councillor breach of duty is disqualification for 5

years whereas Victorian councillors can be liable for an $84,504

fine or 5 years imprisonment.70 These penalties only apply to

gross breaches of duty, such as an undisclosed interest or related

party transaction. Thus council officers spending money unwisely

and taking unwarranted (but legal) perquisites would generally

fall outside of the provisions of state legislation. The relevant

state ombudsman is another option for residents wishing to have

sanctions applied to council staff (but not councillors in Victoria).

However, the ombudsman’s remit is limited: the NSW

Ombudsman is generally unwilling to investigate complaints

regarding the merits of specific development approvals, the

adoption of particular council policies, the striking of rates or the

allocation of council resources, while the Victorian Ombudsman

only hears complaints concerning the ‘administrative action’ of

council staff. It thus seems clear that the existing avenues for

sanctioning councillors and council officers are inadequate with

respect to agency theory.

The NSW Auditor-General recently called for changes to

legislation to give the Office of Local Government ‘greater

powers to intervene, impose greater penalties and demand

compliance’.71 However, it is unclear whether the respective

departments have the judicial bearing and authority to adequately

enforce legislation. Moreover, the NSW Auditor General’s

recommendation could easily politicise disputes. Instead there

would seem to be a sound argument for establishing a dedicated

69 Cutler, Elmendorf and Zeckhauser, above n 22.

70 Audit Office of New South Wales, New South Wales Auditor-

General’s Report Performance Audit – Monitoring Local Government

(2012).

71 Ibid.

164

JOURNAL OF AUSTRALIAN TAXATION

J DREW & B DOLLERY

and politically independent local government ombudsman in each

state, with a broad remit and legislative powers to impose a wide

range of penalties for councillor and staff misconduct, rescind

unconscionable council policy or by-laws, oversee councillor

privileges and disclosures, and otherwise act as an avenue of

appeal for disgruntled residents. Without a dedicated ombudsman

willing to respond on a broad range of matters, it is difficult to see

how trust in council representatives and officials can be

improved.

9. PUBLIC POLICY IMPLICATIONS

As we have seen, Victoria is braced for a rate-capping regime

for its councils commencing in the 2016/17 financial year. Like

all tax limitation measures the proposed rate-cap seeks to place

limits on council monopoly power. In addition, proponents of

rate-pegging suggest that the measure will enhance municipal

efficiency through the fiscal discipline imposed by revenue

constraints. However, the scholarly literature suggests that a rate-

cap will precipitate a number of unintended consequences,

specifically a reduction in the financial sustainability of local

government and a reduction in inter-municipal residential

revenue effort equity.

To date no empirical evidence has been provided in support

of these claims. This paper thus seeks to fill a gap in the

Australian local government literature. In particular, we

conducted a comparative analysis between Victorian and NSW

local government to determine whether almost four decades of

municipal tax limits in NSW had produced any measurable

differences in equity, sustainability or efficiency. We found

evidence which prima facie suggests that NSW councils have

lower levels of inter-municipal residential revenue equity, higher

levels of debt and diminished levels of asset renewals. Our

analysis of efficiency provided no conclusive evidence to support

the claim that rate capping enhances municipal efficiency. We

(2015) 17(1)

165

RATE CAPPING IN LOCAL GOVERNMENT

thus conclude that our analysis provides little support for rate-

capping. Indeed, our findings support the unintended deleterious

consequences cited in the international literature on property tax

limitations.

Against this background, populist politics apart, it is difficult

to understand why the Victorian Government seems determined

to proceed with rate-capping, particularly in light of the ILGRP72

Independent

Local

Government

Review

Panel’s73

recommendation that NSW abandon its rate-pegging regime.

Moreover, the recent announcement of a three-year cap on

Commonwealth FAGs to local government, coupled with

extraordinary superannuation imposts on Victorian councils of

around half a billion dollars suggests that the timing of the

introduction of rate-pegging in Victoria is ill-advised.

Our exploration of alternative methods of addressing the

avenues indicated by personal finance theory and agency theory

suggested several methods by which the Victorian Government

could address the pressures for rate-capping and thereby avoid the

deleterious effects of rate-pegging on Victorian local

government. The remedies indicated by personal finance theory

include encouraging councils to practice user pricing for non-

public services, removing a wide-range of rating exemptions,

providing information on price subsidies, establishing a national

local government infrastructure finance authority, and enabling

councils to implement rate rises incrementally on a quarterly

basis.

Policy alternatives informed by agency theory focus on

reducing information costs for residents (by producing more

detailed information on a timelier basis) and establishing a

dedicated local government ombudsman with broad powers to

sanction elected representatives and officials. If these remedies

72 Independent Local Government Review Panel, above n 3.

73 Ibid.

166

JOURNAL OF AUSTRALIAN TAXATION

J DREW & B DOLLERY

are applied, it may remove the need to implement a potentially

deleterious rate-cap regime.

(2015) 17(1)

167


AustLII: Copyright Policy | Disclaimers | Privacy Policy | Feedback
URL: http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/JlATax/2015/4.html