![]() |
Home
| Databases
| WorldLII
| Search
| Feedback
University of New South Wales Law Journal |
![]() |
[2] Amid the debris, however, there is a growing number of pragmatists, this writer included, who are not yet ready to abandon hope for a concerted and focused international response to the threat posed by global warming. Notwithstanding the US Government’s position, it appears certain that emissions trading will continue to develop and expand in some form as the business and industrial sectors seek more cost-effective ways of reducing greenhouse gas emissions in the years ahead.
[3] The purpose of this short paper is, therefore, to examine the efficacy of emissions trading and its use as a market-based mechanism – it is one of the three ‘flexibility mechanisms’ set out in the Kyoto Protocol – and to consider how an effective emissions trading regime might be developed in the event that the Kyoto Protocol is never ratified, a distinct possibility in the wake of apparent US intransigence on the part of both the Bush Administration and the Republican-controlled Congress.
[4] In the last few years there has been a
relatively rapid increase in the number of jurisdictions incorporating some form
of emissions
trading as part of a domestic regulatory regime for the purpose of
facilitating the achievement of a particular environmental objective.
This leads
one to believe that this type of approach will continue to gain favour, whether
or not the comprehensive global trading regime envisaged under the
Kyoto Protocol is realised. As a starting point, it should be noted that
market-based incentives in general and emissions trading in particular,
evolved
long before the events leading up to the signing of the Kyoto Protocol in
1997 and there is now considerable evidence to suggest that such mechanisms will
continue to form an increasingly important component
of most environmental
regulatory regimes at the domestic, regional, or international level.
[6] The logical extension of these initial programs would be to establish a system of marketable emission permits. Under such a system all major pollution sources of defined pollutants within a given ‘air shed’ would be required to have permits specifying the amount of pollution they are allowed to discharge. Companies which are able to reduce discharges to below their permit levels would be allowed to sell their surplus to other companies. On the other hand, companies for whom compliance is relatively costly could choose instead to purchase additional permits or credits to remain compliant. Over time, a reduction by a specified percentage of overall emissions, or expressed another way, a reduction in total ‘loading’ of defined pollutants from all sources, would be required by law with the result that total emissions would decrease over time.
[7] The principal advantage to participants in such a scheme would be to allow individual polluters to choose their own best cost-efficient strategy for pollution control. Companies would be allowed to trade emission permits, giving them a right to emit a certain quantity of pollutants, or they could pursue other production or abatement strategies that reduced their emissions, whichever would be the most cost effective. In short, each company would be left to decide whether, for that particular corporation, it would be cheaper to reduce emissions or to buy additional permits on the open market. Normal market forces such as supply and demand would determine permit price.[3]
[8] Tradeable emission
permit schemes introduced in recent years in Australia include those associated
with the Bluefin tuna trading
rights, water rights in the Murray-Darling Basin
and the Hunter River salinity trading
scheme.[4]
[10] The COP 6 negotiations failed to obtain agreement on the precise rules and guidelines necessary to develop and/or implement emissions trading under art 17. However, there has nevertheless been substantial agreement on the essential elements which must be addressed to provide the appropriate infrastructure for emissions trading on an international scale among those countries interested in pursuing this option. These include an appropriate method of measuring, monitoring, reporting and verifying emissions by sources, and ‘sequestration’ of greenhouse gases (particularly carbon dioxide) by sinks. Likewise, on the domestic front a number of key issues have been identified concerning the licences or permits to be issued by a government to meet its international commitments under the Kyoto Protocol. These include settling the parameters surrounding permit allocation, permit acquittal, permit design, structure of the market in which the unit is being traded and the legal nature of the unit being traded.[5]
[11] Of equal importance will be the need to ensure that credits generated through the Clean Development Mechanism (‘CDM’) and Joint Implementation (‘JI’) will be readily substituted for nationally traded permits (or units) and ultimately Assigned Amount Units (‘AAUs’) under the Kyoto Protocol. As is the case with all trading regimes, there will be the need to establish a strong compliance system. Experience with domestic commodity markets has shown that that they cannot function efficiently in the absence of a clearly defined set of rules and a high degree of certainty and credibility, which necessarily involves strict enforcement of both rules and obligations. In addition there must be clearly defined legal consequences for violating rules and obligations as a deterrent to deviant behaviour.
[12] Most of the emissions trading activity that has occurred to
date has involved primarily the land-based sequestration side of
the carbon
cycle, namely carbon credits arising from sinks in accordance with the
limitations set out in art 3.3 of the Kyoto Protocol. As a result, much
of the debate surrounding both the CDM and the emissions trading provisions
under the Kyoto Protocol has focused on whether sinks should be included
within the CDM and the degree to which emission credits can be used to offset
domestic
greenhouse gas reduction efforts of the countries listed in Annex I of
the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
(‘UNFCCC’).[6]
[15] The initial work done by the Sydney Futures Exchange following the signing of the Kyoto Protocol in attempting to develop the world’s first exchange-traded market for carbon sequestration credits provides a good example of an evolving public market for emissions trading.[9]
[16] In a somewhat
parallel development, the European Commission published a Climate Action
Plan[10] and a Green
Paper[11] in March 2000 and plans to
commence emissions trading within the EU by 2005. The first European emissions
trading scheme was legislated
by Denmark and approved by the European Commission
on 29 May 2000. This set up a limited trading system for carbon dioxide quotas
between the country’s largest electricity producers.
[18] Even reluctant governments such as the Bush Administration in the US – considered by many to be a hostage of the business community, and in particular the energy industry – may find themselves at odds with the very sector they purport to protect, for it is the business community itself that sees the financial opportunities inherent in an emissions trading regime that ultimately could span the globe.
[19] There now appears to be a determined effort on the part of several countries, most notably those of the EU bloc, Japan, and to a more limited extent Australia, to persuade the US that even if it is not prepared to ratify the Kyoto Protocol, it should not seek to prevent the other signatories from moving forward with a coordinated regional (if not global) response to reduce greenhouse gas emissions in accordance with agreed targets.
[20] Outraged by the failure of the US to embrace the Kyoto Protocol, the emerging strategy of many nations is to explore ways of reaching a strong consensus with other countries which see significant benefits to be derived from the ratification and entry into force of the Kyoto Protocol, either as it stands or with some modifications. Rather than attempting to reverse the US position, there is a growing realisation that their efforts over the next few months could be better spent on evaluating and developing, both individually and collectively, those elements of the Kyoto Protocol which will reduce the burgeoning costs associated with greenhouse gas reduction, in order to achieve their agreed targets. It is in this context that emissions trading will continue to remain at the forefront of the economic market-based incentives endorsed by the vast majority of domestic environmental regulatory regimes, including that of the US, regardless of the fate of the Kyoto Protocol.
[21] Faced with increasing energy costs
and the need to develop cleaner technologies, the business communities of
developed countries
will seek to avail themselves of those mechanisms that
provide an economic incentive to reduce emissions at a lower cost than otherwise
would be the case. It is primarily for this reason that emissions trading will
continue to develop on a limited scale both domestically
and regionally as
various groupings of countries struggle to come to terms with the most serious
environmental threat in our history.
AustLII:
Copyright Policy
|
Disclaimers
|
Privacy Policy
|
Feedback
URL: http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/UNSWLawJl/2001/40.html